Soviet Management Practices
In his entry in Post-Communist Economies, Simon Clarke writes about the management of holding companies in
Even the management structure in the new economy seemed to be a hybrid of Soviet and Capitalist practices. High levels of professionalism and loyalty of the senior managers was a repeated theme. These senior managers often possessed both technical and higher educations. The new managers generally were young and studied abroad for management training. Due to the resentment that often stems from appointing people from the outside to senior positions (because it inhibits promotions), senior managers are either appointed internally or from the holding company’s own staff (Clarke 412). This creates a better working environment for both the company and the common man – the company is happy because the worker is happy, and the worker is happy because of the possibility of a promotion through hard work is now available in a capitalist economy. Naturally this allows for a small, if not a substantial, growth in production and productivity. The ability to climb the proverbial “corporate ladder” is a great incentive for employees to work harder.
Currency and Inflation
One of the major problems that former Soviet states faced was hyperinflation. After the
Nevertheless, in the end the preservation of the ruble zone stabilized. According to scholars John Odling-Smee and Gonzalo Pastor, there were three policy options open for the alternative currency regimes: “a cooperative ruble area arrangement in which all participating central banks would have a say in credit and monetary policy for the ruble area; national currencies; and a Russia-dominated ruble area in which the CBR (Bank of Russia) would be solely responsible for monetary and exchange rate issues” (quoted in Åslund 50). Obviously the Russia-dominated ruble area was politically impossible, and people would question if the Soviet Union truly had broken up. By the end of 1991, all of the fifteen Soviet republics had set up their own central banks and began issuing money, independently of the other banks, including the Soviet Gosbank (Åslund 50).
Currently all of these former Soviet states have their own independent national currencies. The introduction of these national currencies helped financially stabilize each nation. The three aforementioned Baltic countries that created their national currencies first were also the first economies to stabilize (Åslund 50). Even though the national currencies were successful in stabilizing their own economies, it did lead to some problems. The fifteen banks were competing with one another in issuing credits. The more credits one bank or country issued, the bank or country received a larger share of the total GDP. The smaller republics could not issue as much money and therefore obtained a smaller share of the common GDP (Åslund 50-51). This clearly is a handicap to the smaller or poorer nations. That is one reason why the Baltic nations insisted on a national currency and introducing it as early as possible. It was believed to be impossible to control monetary production by more than one central bank in one currency zone through a cooperative agreement (Åslund 51). Through false reporting and the illegality of electronic payments, the Soviet republics did not trust each other and felt that mutual cheating was the only logical approach. It was obvious that a cooperative monetary system in one ruble zone was impossible to implement, and by breaking up the ruble zone, separate national currencies emerged to be the best alternative (Åslund 51).
Besides
Robert S. Kravchuk writes, “The former Soviet Republic of Ukraine has suffered the worst of what economic transition has to offer” (Kravchuk 45). His evidence includes the country’s decreasing economic production in output, employment, productivity, and investment. During the two year period of 1991-1993,
How did the Ukrainian government benefit from inflation and not collapse in the face of adversity? Kravchuk suggests John Maynard Keynes’ theory that governments in general raise their revenues by purposefully inflating their currencies. Keynes wrote that a nation’s ability to “live for a long time… by printing paper money” and “live by this means when it can live by no other” (Kravchuk 54). This tactic essentially deceives the public as to the basic value of its monetary assets. The exclusive right for a government to issue new money is called seigniorage. The depreciation of existing money balances since the newly issued money is termed the inflation tax. The actual change in monetary holdings, or real balances, is equal to the sum of seigniorage and the inflation tax (Kravchuk 54). The combination of seigniorage and the “new” inflation tax help deceive, or cover up, the government’s weakening currency. Domestically, this is a brilliant way to mislead the public; internationally, the national currency becomes more worthless.
The Ukrainian government should be applauded in their conversion efforts; approximately 95.5 percent of circulated cash was converted between September 2 and 16 (Kravchuk 62). The new currency also proved strong from its inception – the Ukrainian Interbank Currency Exchange reported that the hryvna started trading at 1.76 to the dollar, holding through October and slowly rising to 1.82 per dollar in November and 1.88 in December. Even the Russian currency exchanged at 3,000 rubles per hryvna and 1.18 to the Deutsch Mark (Kravchuk 63). It is extremely impressive that the Ukrainian currency proved to be significantly stronger than the Russian ruble. The elimination of dollarization and currency inflation via a new, stronger currency greatly assisted the Ukrainian economy. A stronger currency allows a nation to open its trading doors to other countries that may have been skeptical about the worth of their products and currency inflation, thus promoting economic growth through exports.
Dollarization and
In addition to the issues of national currencies and stabilizing economies, dollarization can sometimes help control inflation. Dollarization is the use of any economically stable foreign currency as a country’s unofficial national currency. The
Visible forms of dollarization, that is, forms that can be measured, are cash dollarization, deposit/asset dollarization, and liability dollarization (Havrylyshyn & Beddies 331). Why does dollarization occur? Currency inflation is usually the primary reason; when the use of domestic currency for purchases and transactions is too high due to the lack of confidence in the local currency, it motivates the public to adopt a more reliable currency. Even more than a decade after these former Soviet states gained independence, the amount of dollarization is relatively high and even rising in some countries. Expectantly dollarization is lowest in the Baltics at 27 percent with the average rate of dollarization approximately 35 percent among the former Soviet states, and as high as 52 percent in
There are several costly consequences of dollarization. It leads to the lower demand of domestic money because of reduced credibility in the local currency, forgone tax revenue through underground economic activity, and a facilitation of crime and corruption. Accounting for macroeconomic instability, dollarization can also lead to high inflation and depreciating exchange rates (Havrylyshyn & Beddies 330). Despite these negative aspects of dollarization, it does have an upside. Most studies initially believed that dollarization was harmful, but now indicate that it is not as damaging as previously thought and actually has a beneficial dimension in promoting the growth of financial market developments (Havrylyshyn & Beddies 329). This growth of financial market developments is made possible through better portfolio diversification, which can then reduce or even reverse capital flight. Since dollarization occurs as a free choice by rational economic agents, it can be used as an inflation-beating strategy (Havrylyshyn & Beddies 330).
The use of a foreign nation’s currency is not a new trend. Its classic form appeared during the hyperinflation period in
The legality behind dollarization began in
However, as a result there was an increase in demand for foreign currencies and continuing dollarization in
The impact of dollarization is evident – although it may lead to a small beneficial role in the economy, for the most part it makes countries more dependent on the foreign currency. As shown with
Macroeconomic Performance: GDP & TFP
Economic growth has a substantial impact on a nation’s economic performance. Even with the fairly successful transition of the Ukrainian economy, currently some of the former Soviet republics are still experiencing economic regression and contraction. These regions have experience a substantial drop in GDP growth since 1990, and in some cases the transition economies barely recovered to pre-transition GDP levels as recently as five years ago.
Ertuğrul Deliktaş and Mehmet Balcilar estimate efficiency measures for twenty-five Baltic and Eastern European countries, including former Soviet republics utilizing stochastic frontier analysis (SFA)[1] and data envelopment analysis as a confirmatory study to determine if the transition to a market-based economy increased in total factor productivity (TFP)[2], economic efficiency, and technical progress (Deliktaş & Balcilar 6). The mean annual efficiency level for the 25 transition economies is 0.548, and the yearly rate of growth in technical efficiency is 1.8 percent between 1991 and 2000. However, the mean annual technical change in those economies is -4.3 percent; there is zero technological progress, which actually equates to technological regress (Deliktaş & Balcilar 6). Some of these nations are having difficulties, leading to taking a step back rather than a step forward in their transition to a market economy.
As previously mentioned, economic growth is the primary objective in a nation’s economic policy. The absence of economic growth can become a barrier in curbing a nation’s long-term poverty (Deliktaş & Balcilar 7). Table 1 (attached) from Deliktaş’ and Balcilar’s study shows the annual mean GDP growth rate of these transition economies between 1990 and 2000 (Deliktaş & Balcilar 8). According to Table 1, only seven nations, including
There are three major factors that economists use in determining the economic performance of a nation. The first focuses on growth in real per capita GDP, also known as real per capita income. It is a first hand indicator that is associated with the standard of living. The other two factors are the disparities in the distribution of income among poor countries and the average productivity performance of workers, such as output per person employed or per hour worked, along with “multifactor productivity measures based on the concept of total factor productivity (TFP) and its components…”(Deliktaş & Balcilar 7).
Slow and regressing GDP rates obviously have a considerable effect on a nation’s GDP per capita levels.
Conclusion
In summation, there exist numerous barriers for the transformation from a socialist to a capitalist market economy. Incentives such as promotions, the restructuring of management, and utilizing a punishment and reward system can lead to more productive workers. Emulating a capitalist workplace through both internal management of businesses and methods of conflict resolution can achieve better economic production. Eliminating hyperinflation and currency inflation through the use of either a new domestic currency or establishing noncompetitive central banks can help stabilize a transitioning economy. Separate national currencies are the best alternative because of the false reports of “cheating” banks in the failed ruble zone. Unlike the Ukrainian government, avoiding seigniorage and economic dependence with other Soviet states is a key move in obtaining an economy without holes in resources and exports. Strict regulation of dollarization can help prevent the otherwise negative consequences of high inflation rates, loss of confidence in the domestic currency, and black markets. Economic growth is by far the primary objective for any nation, especially since it is linked directly to the standard of living and poverty of a country. The transition to a market economy can be extremely difficult, but as we have seen through
[1] The econometric methods (SFA) can be classified as (1) those that assume all deviations from the frontier are due to inefficiencies, and (2) those that allow some variation around the frontier due to factors that cannot be controlled by the firm. In the first method, a deterministic frontier is prescribed, while a scholastic frontier is prescribed in the second. Econometric methods allow flexible functional forms for the frontier and impose some restriction on the statistical properties of efficiency terms (Balcilar and Cokgezen 2001, quoted Deliktaş & Balcilar 12).
[2] Productivity and economic growth are important because they determine the real standard of living that a country can achieve for its citizens. There is a simple link between a nation’s productivity growth and standard of living. TFP growth is simply the sum of efficiency and technical changes. These two changes constitute the TFP change index (Balcilar and Cokgezen 2001, quoted Deliktaş & Balcilar 12).
1 comment:
These are lengthy! I am impressed.
Post a Comment